Saturday, January 31, 2009

Summers vs Obama

The analysis of Professor Larry Summers:
Another cause of long-term unemployment is unionization. High union wages that exceed the competitive market rate are likely to cause job losses in the unionized sector of the economy. Also, those who lose high-wage union jobs are often reluctant to accept alternative low-wage employment. Between 1970 and 1985, for example, a state with a 20 percent unionization rate, approximately the average for the fifty states and the District of Columbia, experienced an unemployment rate that was 1.2 percentage points higher than that of a hypothetical state that had no unions.
The policies of President Barack Obama:

On the economy, President Barack Obama signaled once again the ground is shifting -- this time with regard to unions.

With his signature on three executive orders, President Barack Obama expanded workers rights and reversed Bush administration orders that were seen as anti-union.

Then, the president said something that hasn't been heard in the Oval Office for a long time. "I do not view the labor movement as part of the problem, to me it's part of the solution," said President Obama.

Smoot, Hawley, & Pelosi

The Washington Post reports:

The stimulus bill passed by the House last night contains a controversial provision that would mostly bar foreign steel and iron from the infrastructure projects laid out by the $819 billion economic package.

A Senate version, yet to be acted upon, goes further, requiring, with few exceptions, that all stimulus-funded projects use only American-made equipment and goods....

U.S. industrial giants including Caterpillar, General Electric and the domestic aerospace industry are emerging as strong opponents. The measures, they argue, could violate trade deals the United States has signed in recent years, including an agreement on expanding access to government procurements reached through the World Trade Organization.

But most damaging, critics say, would be the "protectionist message" attached to imposing such barriers on foreign companies.Nations including China and many in Europe are preparing to spend billions of dollars of taxpayer money on stimulus projects. American companies are angling for a piece of those pies, and retaliatory measures against U.S. companies, executives argue, could significantly complicate those efforts. This week, a European Commission spokesman threatened countermeasures if the Buy American provisions are approved.

I hope President Obama and his economists strongly oppose these first shots in a new trade war of protectionism. So far, the article says, "the administration has not addressed the issue publicly."

Thursday, January 29, 2009

The Malkiel Portfolio

I took introductory macroeconomics from Burt Malkiel at Princeton (in 1977, just after he returned from a stint at the Council of Economic Advisers) and learned my early lessons in finance from reading his book, A Random Walk Down Wall Street. So I was interested in reading about his latest portfolio recommendations:
  • 20% Vanguard Total Stock Market ETF (VTI) (Tracks a broad index of U.S. companies)
  • 20% Vanguard FTSE All-World ex-US ETF (VEU) (Tracks a broad index of stocks from developed and emerging foreign markets.)
  • 20% Vanguard Total Bond Market ETF (BND) (Tracks a broad index of high-quality U.S. bonds)
  • 10% Vanguard Capital Opportunity (VHCOX) (An actively managed fund that likes big growth companies down on their luck)
  • 10% Vanguard Emerging Markets ETF (VWO) (Tracks an index of stocks developing nations)
  • 10% Templeton Dragon (TDF) (Invests in stocks from China and nearby nations)
  • 10% Matthew's India (MINDX) (Invests in stocks from India)
Compared to what I expected, Burt has more in equities in general and more in emerging markets in particular. (Emerging markets include the last three holdings on his list, plus a bit of the second, making up about a third of the total portfolio). To my surprise, he lists no specific allocation to real estate securities such as REITS or to inflation-protected bonds.

Wednesday, January 28, 2009

Judging Presidents

A reader asks a good question:

What are some useful and objective measures which we can use to judge the performance of President Obama and his new team? How would Greg Mankiw judge Obama four years from now?
Consider a related question: How would you judge the competence of a doctor if you could observe him treating only a single patient?



What you would not do is judge him by the outcome. Even the best physicians have patients die. And even witchdoctors can have patients recover. Randomness is a fact of life (and death). In the case of a medical doctor, the answer seems clear: Instead of looking at the outcome, you would judge him by the decisions he makes and treatments he prescribes. That is, you would examine whether he followed best practices for the circumstances he faced.



Similarly, randomness is a fact of economic life, and it would be a mistake to judge a president by the economic outcome during his administration. It is better to look at the decisions the president made, and to acknowledge that the outcome is a function of those decisions and many other factors not under his control. As an economist, I have views about what best practices are for economic policy, and I judge presidents by how closely they adhere to those principles.



Unfortunately, that evaluation process is not quite as simple and objective as the reader might have hoped for. But I don't think there is a better alternative.



Now some people may be tempted to read the above commentary and call it self-serving. After all, the economy looks pretty bad right now, so maybe I am trying to excuse President Bush and, indirectly, myself as one of his economic advisers.



Not so. If you want to judge presidents and their economic advisers by outcomes, that would be all to my benefit. I arrived in Washington to head the CEA in February 2003 and left in February 2005. (Harvard has a two-year rule for faculty leave). During that time, the economy grew at a healthy annualized rate of 3.6 percent, and the unemployment rate fell half a percentage point. As judged by outcomes, I look pretty good! But I will be the first to admit that this argument is deeply silly.

Stein and Liebman to DC

The Crimson reports that the Obama administration has recruited Harvard economists Jeremy Stein and Jeff Liebman, both excellent choices.

Tuesday, January 27, 2009

Krugman on Equilibrium Macro

Paul Krugman disses a large class of macroeconomists:
Economists who have spent their entire careers on equilibrium business cycle theory are now discovering, in effect, that they invested their savings with Bernie Madoff.
It is funny. I have a similar pedigree as Paul. Both of us have PhDs from MIT, and we learned a lot of our macro there. Both of us see the world through the lens of the Keynesian framework (by which I mean the IS-LM model, etc.) But we have very different perspectives on the equilibrium business cycle theorists.

The difference may reflect our research paths. Most of Paul's research has been in international economics, and throughout his career, he could easily ignore equilibrium business cycle theory. By contrast, I have done a lot of work on "new Keynesian economics," which tries to fix the flaws in the Keynesian model that the equilibrium business cycle theorists pointed out. Perhaps that work has given me more appreciation for their contribution, as well as for the defects in the Keynesian worldview. When I teach graduate-level macro, no one shows up on my reading list more often than Robert Lucas, the father of equilibrium macro.

In my view, the intellectual framework created by Lucas and Ed Prescott needs to be taken seriously by students of modern macro. I think they both richly deserved the Nobel Prize. And I hope they did not invest any of their winnings with Bernie Madoff.

Amusing, Perhaps Pointless

The Bailout Game

Penny Anti Protest: Update

Here.

CBO on Fiscal Policy Lags

From CBO, here is the time path of estimated outlays on government purchases under the proposed stimulus bill:

2009: 29.0
2010: 115.8
2011: 105.5
2012: 53.6
2013: 26.5
2014: 13.0
2015: 6.9
2016: 3.0
2017: 1.6
2018: 0.9
2019:0.4

Total: $356.0 billion

So only 8 percent of this spending occurs in budget year 2009, and only 41 percent occurs in first two years. Note that spending on transfer payments and tax relief occurs much faster than this: click through to the above link for details.

Shiller on Animal Spirits

Yale's Bob Shiller argues that confidence is the key to getting the economy back on track.

I think a lot of economists would agree with that. The question is what it would take to make people more confident. Bob thinks that confidence would rise if the government borrowed more and spent more. Other economists think that confidence would rise if the government committed itself to, say, lower taxes on capital income. The sad truth is that we economists don't know very much about what drives the animal spirits of economic participants. Until we figure it out, it is best to be suspicious of any policy whose benefits are supposed to work through the amorphous channel of "confidence."

Monday, January 26, 2009

The Mature Keynesian Perspective

Via NYU prof Mario Rizzo, here is John Maynard Keynes of 1942, six years after The General Theory:
Organized public works, at home and abroad, may be the right cure for a chronic tendency to a deficiency of effective demand. But they are not capable of sufficiently rapid organisation (and above all cannot be reversed or undone at a later date), to be the most serviceable instrument for the prevention of the trade cycle.

Cochrane on Fiscal Stimulus

A thought-provoking piece by University of Chicago economist John Cochrane. His bottom line:
there is a plausible diagnosis and a logically consistent argument under which fiscal stimulus could help: We are experiencing a strong portfolio and precautionary demand for government debt, along with a credit crunch. People want to hold less private debt and they want to save, and they want to hold Treasuries, money, or government-guaranteed debt. However, this demand can be satisfied in far greater quantity, much more quickly, much more reversibly, and without the danger of a fiscal collapse and inflation down the road, if the Fed and Treasury were simply to expand their operations of issuing treasury debt and money in exchange for high-quality private debt and especially new securitized debt.
Updates: Phill Swagel, who until recently was Assistant Secretary of the Treasury for Economic Policy, emails me this observation:
The bit you posted from John Cochrane is precisely what the TALF is about -- the joint Treasury-Fed facility aimed at securitized assets (consumer lending at first, but it could be scaled up to non-agency RMBS and CMBS).

Thanks, Phill.

Around the econoblogosphere, John's piece is proving controversial. Harvard's Dani Rodik calls it the "best argument against a conventional fiscal stimulus that I have seen" and notes "since it is also very well written every macroeconomics student should read it in full." Meanwhile, Berkeley's Brad DeLong accuses John of making "an elementary, freshman mistake."

Aid Watch

Bill Easterly, one of my favorite development economists, has started a blog.

Listen to me squawk

I was on CNBC's Squawkbox this morning.

Saturday, January 24, 2009

CEA Confirmation Hearings

Click here to watch the confirmation hearing for the three new members of the Council of Economic Advisers. The CEA comes second on this video. Click ahead to around minute 223.

Friday, January 23, 2009

A Discussion Question

The NY Times reports that the new president is concerned about how banks are using TARP funds:
[President Obama] criticized companies that have used federal money they received under the financial bailout for low priority or wasteful purposes and promised not to let that happen. He cited “reports that we’ve seen over the last couple of days about companies that have received taxpayer assistance, then going out and renovating bathrooms or offices, or in other ways not managing those dollars appropriately.”

A prominent economist emails me the following:

Discussion question.

Scenario 1. AmeriBank of Holland, Ohio, receives TARP funds and uses $20,000 to hire Joe the Plumber to remodel a bathroom in one of its banks.

Scenario 2. AmeriBank of Holland, Ohio, receives TARP funds and loans $20,000 to Bob the Baker to remodel a bathroom in his house.

Explain the difference in macroeconomic stimulus in these two scenarios.

We're Hot, Not

Crooked Timber presents this ranking of academic fields, based on the "hotness" ratings at RateMyProfessors. We econ profs don't do so well. Hmmm...maybe I should have finished that law degree I started.

FYI, here is my ratings page, which makes me wonder whether any student takes this activity seriously.

Is Joe Biden disingenuous or misinformed?

In a TV interview last month, Vice President Joe Biden said the following:
Every economist, as I've said, from conservative to liberal, acknowledges that direct government spending on a direct program now is the best way to infuse economic growth and create jobs.
That statement is clearly false. As I have documented on this blog in recent weeks, skeptics about a spending stimulus include quite a few well-known economists, such as (in alphabetical order) Alberto Alesina, Robert Barro, Gary Becker, John Cochrane, Eugene Fama, Robert Lucas, Greg Mankiw, Kevin Murphy, Thomas Sargent, Harald Uhlig, and Luigi Zingales--and I am sure there many others as well. Regardless of whether one agrees with them on the merits of the case, it is hard to dispute that this list is pretty impressive, as judged by the standard objective criteria by which economists evaluate one another. If any university managed to hire all of them, it would immediately have a top ranked economics department.

So what is one to make of the vice president's statement? As a logical matter, I can think of only four possibilities:
  1. Biden knew what he was saying was false.
  2. Biden was saying what he believed to be true and somehow got this incorrect idea in his head without talking about the issue with the very talented team of economists working for the new administration.
  3. Biden talked to his economic advisers about the issue, and they purposefully misled him into thinking that there was a consensus among economists, even though there isn't.
  4. Biden's advisers were themselves mistaken. They expected an overwhelming consensus of support for their fiscal plans and were surprised at the number of prominent economists on the opposite side the issue.
I have no idea which of these hypotheses is correct. I suspect it is either the first or last. But any one of them should make us uneasy about how well the new administration's economic decisionmaking apparatus is working.

Update: A reader emails me a fifth hypothesis. Earlier in the same interview, Biden refers to "every economist that I've spoken to," and maybe that is the group he is referring to in this later quotation as well. In that case, as the reader suggests, "Biden needs to speak to a broader circle of economists."

Huizinga, Lucas, and Murphy

Click here to watch a great panel discussion from the University of Chicago about the economy and proposed fiscal plans.

Thursday, January 22, 2009

Barro on Fiscal Stimulus

From my Harvard colleague Robert Barro:

in terms of fiscal-stimulus proposals, it would be unfortunate if the best Team Obama can offer is an unvarnished version of Keynes's 1936 "General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money." The financial crisis and possible depression do not invalidate everything we have learned about macroeconomics since 1936.

Much more focus should be on incentives for people and businesses to invest, produce and work. On the tax side, we should avoid programs that throw money at people and emphasize instead reductions in marginal income-tax rates -- especially where these rates are already high and fall on capital income. Eliminating the federal corporate income tax would be brilliant. On the spending side, the main point is that we should not be considering massive public-works programs that do not pass muster from the perspective of cost-benefit analysis.

---

Update: Paul Krugman calls Barro's piece "boneheaded." Tyler Cowen comes to Barro's defense.

Wednesday, January 21, 2009

Why Major in Economics?

The answer from a Goldin and Katz analysis of Harvard graduates:

The most lucrative college major is economics, which has an earnings premium of 0.33 log points and a premium of 0.19 including occupation controls.

Questions for Tim Geithner

From seven experts. Anna Schwartz's first question gets the award for Most Pointed.

Alesina and Zingales on Fiscal Stimulus

From Harvard economist Alberto Alesina and University of Chicago economist Luigi Zingales:

Many are concerned about what we can do to help the poor weather this crisis. Unlike during the Great Depression, we have an unemployment subsidy that protects the poor from the most severe consequences of this recession. If we want to further protect them, it is better to extend this unemployment subsidy than to invest in hasty public projects. Furthermore, tax cuts have a much better effect on job creation than highway
rehabilitation.

Time to Switch

With a new president just having moved into the White House, I remind my fellow bloggers of Jane's Law:

The devotees of the party in power are smug and arrogant. The devotees of the party out of power are insane.

Tuesday, January 20, 2009

The Long Lags of Fiscal Policy

The AP reports:

Much in Obama stimulus bill won't hit economy soon

WASHINGTON -- It will take years before an infrastructure spending program proposed by President-elect Barack Obama will boost the economy, according to congressional economists.

The findings, released to lawmakers Sunday, call into question the effectiveness of congressional Democrats' efforts to pump up the economy through old-fashioned public works projects like roads, bridges and repairs of public housing.

Less than half of the $30 billion in highway construction funds detailed by House Democrats would be released into the economy over the next four years, concludes the analysis by the Congressional Budget Office. Less than $4 billion in highway construction money would reach the economy by September 2010.

The economy has been in recession for more than a year, but many economists believe a recovery may begin by the end of 2009. That would mean that most of the infrastructure money wouldn't hit the economy until it's already on the mend.

The CBO analysis doesn't cover tax cuts or efforts by Democrats to provide relief to cash-strapped state governments to help with their Medicaid bills. But it illustrates just how difficult it can be to use public investment to rush money into the economy. It usually takes bids and contracts to announce such developments, which invariably take time.

Overall, only $26 billion out of $274 billion in infrastructure spending would be delivered into the economy by the Sept. 30 end of the budget year, just 7 percent. Just one in seven dollars of a huge $18.5 billion investment in energy efficiency and renewable energy programs would be spent within a year and a half.

Godspeed, President Obama

Mountford and Uhlig on Fiscal Policy

I mentioned an earlier version of this paper a while back, but a reader emails me that it is now available as an NBER Working Paper.

What are the Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks?

---- Abstract -----
We propose and apply a new approach for analyzing the effects of fiscal policy using vector autoregressions. Specifically, we use sign restrictions to identify a government revenue shock as well as a government spending shock, while controlling for a generic business cycle shock and a monetary policy shock. We explicitly allow for the possibility of announcement effects, i.e., that a current fiscal policy shock changes fiscal policy variables in the future, but not at present. We construct the impulse responses to three linear combinations of these fiscal shocks, corresponding to the three scenarios of deficit-spending, deficit-financed tax cuts and a balanced budget spending expansion. We apply the method to US quarterly data from 1955-2000. We find that deficit-financed tax cuts work best among these three scenarios to improve GDP, with a maximal present value multiplier of five dollars of total additional GDP per each dollar of the total cut in government revenue five years after the shock.

Monday, January 19, 2009

A Penny Anti Protest

My regular readers know that I favor eliminating the penny, and that Barack Obama is sympathetic to the idea. Professor Robert Whaples of Wake Forest alerts me to a blog posting that suggests a way to reach this goal:
Retailers should simply round down the total checkout tally for cash purchasers and not handle pennies at all. There will be no need for pennies in change and anyone who wants to use pennies to pay, can put them in a charity jar instead. The first retailer to do this will reap a PR bonanza and others will quickly follow. Within a couple of years, retailers who don’t round down will be as rare as those who don’t accept credit cards. Not getting pennies in change, like being able to pay with credit cards, will be considered a birthright.
And then, later in the comments section, the following update is added, suggesting that the movement has begun:

Concord Teacakes found this posting and is going to DO IT.

In Concord, MA (The birthplace of Civil Disobedience), on February 12 (LIncoln’s 200th birthday) they are going to refuse pennies, starting at (time subject to change) 9:00 AM. Be there — it’s opposite the West Concord train station.

Advice for Tim Geithner

From University of Chicago economist Luigi Zingales.

Krugman on Stimulus Skeptics

Paul Krugman is unhappy with the economics profession:
What’s been disturbing, however, is the parade of first-rate economists making totally non-serious arguments against fiscal expansion. You’ve got John Taylor arguing for permanent tax cuts as a response to temporary shocks, apparently oblivious to the logical problems. You’ve got John Cochrane going all Andrew-Mellon-liquidationist on us. You’ve got Eugene Fama reinventing the long-discredited Treasury View. You’ve got Gary Becker apparently unaware that monetary policy has hit the zero lower bound. And you’ve got Greg Mankiw — well, I don’t know what Greg actually believes, he just seems to be approvingly linking to anyone opposed to stimulus, regardless of the quality of their argument.
If Paul really wants to know what I believe, he can read what I have written on the subject.

Let me make one thing clear: When I link to another economist here on this blog, it is typically because I think his or her arguments are worth hearing and thinking about, not necessarily because I agree with all of them. I don't have the time (and, in some cases, expertise) to offer a refereeing service for every article I mention. So when I say, "Here is an article by Professor X," I mean "Here is an article by Professor X," not "Here is an article by Professor X, and I approve of everything he says."

In recent weeks, I have linked to Christy Romer making the case for the Obama fiscal stimulus as well as many economists on the opposite side the debate. It is true that I have linked more to those opposed. That is partly a reflection of my opinion on the issue. It is also partly to provide a counterpoint to the view disingenuously promoted by some members of the incoming administration that almost all major economists are lined up behind their stimulus plans. As Paul's list of prominent stimulus skeptics documents well, that is simply not the case.

Infrastructure Spending as Stimulus

From Nobel laureate Gary Becker:

Some of this infrastructure spending may be very worthwhile-I return to this issue a bit later- but however merited, it is difficult to believe that they would provide much of a stimulus to the economy. Expansion of the health sector, for example, will add jobs to this sector, but it will do this mainly by drawing people into the health care sector who are presently employed in jobs outside this sector. This is because unemployment rates among health care workers are quite low, and most of the unemployed who had worked in construction, finance, or manufacturing are unlikely to qualify as health care workers without considerable additional training. This same conclusion applies to spending on expanding broadband, to make the energy used greener, to encourage new technologies and more research, and to improve teaching.

An analysis by Forbes publications of where most jobs will be created singles out engineering, accounting, nursing, and information technology, along with construction managers, computer-aided drafting specialists, and project managers. Unemployment rates among most of these specialists are not high. The rebuilding of "crumbling roads, bridges, and schools" highlighted by in various speeches by President Obama is likely to make greater use of unemployed workers in the construction sector. However, such spending will be a small fraction of the total stimulus package, and it is not easy for workers who helped build residential housing to shift to building highways.

A second crucial issue relates not to the amount of new output and employment created by the stimulus, but to the efficiency of the government spending. Efficiency is not likely to be high partly because of the fundamental conflict between the goal of stimulating employment and output in order to reduce the severity of the recession, and the goal of concentrating infrastructure spending on projects that add a lot of value to the economy. Stimulating the economy when employment is falling requires rapid spending of this huge stimulus package, but it is impossible for either the private or public sectors to spend effectively a large amount in a short time period since good spending takes a lot of planning time.

Putting new infrastructure spending in depressed areas like Detroit might have a big stimulating effect since infrastructure building projects in these areas can utilize some of the considerable unemployed resources there. However, many of these areas are also declining because they have been producing goods and services that are not in great demand, and will not be in demand in the future. Therefore, the overall value added by improving their roads and other infrastructure is likely to be a lot less than if the new infrastructure were located in growing areas that might have relatively little unemployment, but do have great demand for more roads, schools, and other types of long-term infrastructure.

Sunday, January 18, 2009

Economists for Wheelan

The author of Naked Economics is running for Congress on the following platform:

At a time of unique challenges to the global financial system, it is imperative to have members of Congress with a sophisticated understanding of economics.

Economic stimulus that includes government spending should be carefully designed to ensure that only projects that have social value are funded. Infrastructure projects, identified by an objective panel, that likely would have been pursued without special funds are good candidates. If there are insufficient projects meeting a high cost-benefit threshold, additional stimulus should come in the form of tax cuts.

Any mitigation of greenhouse gas emissions in the United States should be pursued through market mechanisms that raise revenue, which can be used to reduce the personal, corporate and/or payroll tax.

The U.S. should make long-term investments in human capital, particularly in early childhood education for low-income and disadvantaged children.

Congress should promote free trade and work to reduce trade barriers around the globe. The best way to deal with the political costs of trade and the economic dislocation caused by international competition is to create a meaningful safety net for displaced workers.

Tax reform is necessary to improve the equity, efficiency and simplicity of the tax code. A priority of tax reform should be a reduction in the number of special incentives that narrow the tax base, induce tax avoidance and increase compliance costs.

The U.S. must deal with the looming fiscal obligations created by our entitlement programs: Medicare, Medicaid, and Social Security. Our current economic situation justifies increased deficits now, but today's policy must be attentive to the need for fiscal balance over the next several decades.

If you agree, you can endorse these ideas here.

Saturday, January 17, 2009

Life Before Ec 10

Obama rejects the Pigou Club

The Washington Post's Steve Mufson reports:
Goodness knows, President-elect Obama has his legislative hands full. Maybe that explains why he has taken the idea of increasing gasoline taxes off the table, saying that Americans had enough economic burdens at the moment. Nominees like Steven Chu, the Nobel Prize winning physicist who will become Energy Secretary, dutifully echoed Obama's view even though in Chu's case he has long supported higher fuel taxes.

Continue reading here.

ERP

Click here for the just released Economic Report of the President.

Friday, January 16, 2009

The Brain Science of Irrational Exuberance

David Brooks reports:
As Andrew Lo of M.I.T. has demonstrated, if stock traders make a series of apparently good picks, the dopamine released into their brains creates a stupor that causes them to underperceive danger ahead.
FYI, the new and growing field of neuroeconomics makes two appearances in the the latest edition of my favorite textbook. If you have a copy, check the index.

Update: More on the biological roots of the financial crisis.

How to Become a Trillionaire

Move to a hyperinflating country:
Zimbabwe is introducing a Z$100 trillion note, currently worth about US$30.

More Spending Stimulus Skeptics

The Chicago Tribune reports:

John Cochrane, a professor at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, says that among academics over the last 30 years, the idea of fiscal stimulus has been discredited and in graduate courses, it is "taught only for its fallacies."

New York University economist Thomas Sargent agrees: "The calculations that I have seen supporting the stimulus package are back-of-the-envelope ones that ignore what we have learned in the last 60 years of macroeconomic research."

Wednesday, January 14, 2009

Fama on Fiscal Stimulus

Eugene Fama is a stimulus skeptic.

In fact, he is even more skeptical than I am. I am willing to concede that many Keynesian effects work in the short run, although I prefer monetary policy to fiscal policy and, within fiscal policy, I prefer the use of tax instruments to government spending as a tool for short-run demand management. By contrast, I read Fama's article as a largely wholesale endorsement of the classical model with complete crowding out.

Update: Brad DeLong takes me to task for not taking Fama to task:

No, Greg. It's not an endorsement of any model. It's just a mistake. Fama mistakes the NIPA savings-investment accounting identity for a behavioral relationship that constrains the behavior of investment: when the government deficit goes up, Fama says, private investment must go down by the same amount.

When the government deficit goes up, private savings could go up by more--and private investment could increase. Private savings could go up by less--and private investment would fall by less than the rise in the government deficit. Private savings could remain unchanged. Or private savings could fall. Determining which of these is most likely to happen would require a model of the economy of some sort--and Fama does not have one: all he has is an accounting identity that he does not understand.

This post reflects a fundamental difference between Brad's approach to the world and mine. When I read others' work, I try to read between the lines and put it in the best possible light. In particular, when I read the work of an economist as distinguished as Eugene Fama, I am reluctant to jump to the conclusion that I am vastly smarter than he is.

In the case at hand, I think Fama's arguments make sense in the context of the classical model, the model presented in Chapter 3 of my intermediate macro textbook, even if Fama in his brief essay does not spell out all the details of that model. Unlike Fama, and like Brad, I would not stop at that model. To understand the present situation, I would go on to the Keynesian model presented in Chapter 9 to 11. But whether one leaves the classical model behind to embrace the Keynesian model is a judgment call. On this particular judgment call, Brad and I agree, but I am not eager to castigate those like Fama who reach differing judgments.

Ted is more relaxed

Bloomberg reports that the Ted spread is now below 100 basis points. The Ted spread, the difference between the interest rates on interbank loans and T-bills, is one gauge of how much fear is gripping the financial system. Its decline suggests that the TARP is working and is certainly good news.

Tuesday, January 13, 2009

Triangles vs Gaps

A smart reader (who, because of his current job, prefers anonymity) offers this input about the recent debate over fiscal stimulus:
I've enjoyed your stirring the pot on the great stimulus discussion in recent weeks. One thing I haven't seen much discussion of is the idea that there are intertemporal tradeoffs involved. Suppose, for purposes of discussion, that stimulus does actually work, but that taxpayers do ultimately have to pay for it. In that case, there is a tradeoff between increasing economic welfare in the short-run and reducing economic welfare in the long-run (because of the distortions of raising taxes). Are there any well-established macro models that provide some guidance on how that balancing should be done? Many analysts seem to believe that the stimulus should be sized to close as much of the output gap as possible. But it isn't obvious to me that's true if, in a perfect world, we are balancing the short-term gains against long run costs.
The reader is right that this consideration has not gotten much attention of late. Why? I suspect the answer is that those who are most confident in Keynesian policy prescriptions are most skeptical about the distortionary effects of taxation. To put it perhaps a bit too bluntly, the Keynesian mutliplier is about income effects, while neoclassical tax distortions are about substitution effects. For those of us eclectic enough to see the world including a variety of effects, both Keynesian and neoclassical, policy decisions are far harder than they are for those eager to focus on one effect while setting the other close to zero. You can guess which effect those on the far left and those on the far right choose to focus on.

Jim Tobin once addressed this issue, saying, "It takes a heap of Harberger triangles to fill an Okun's gap."* That is a great slogan for the Keynesian team. But I agree with the reader that it would be better to go beyond quips and try to quantify the issue with real data and real models. (PhD students: Take note of a possible dissertation topic.) In light of the looming tax increases that may well occur over the next few decades to finance promised entitlement programs for the elderly, Harburger triangles loom larger now than they did in Tobin's day.
-----
* For economists under the age of 40, who may be less familiar with these archaic terms: A Harberger triangle is the area in a supply and demand diagram that measures the deadweight loss of taxation. An Okun's gap is the loss in output and employment when the economy falls below potential because of insufficient aggregate demand.

A Note of Optimism

Stanford's Nick Bloom and Max Floetotto say, "economic uncertainty is now dropping so rapidly that we believe growth will resume by mid-2009."

Small-Government Egalitarianism

The latest from Ed Glaeser.

Fresh Air

Terry Gross interviews one of my favorite economists.

Unconventional Monetary Policy

A nice overview from Glenn Rudebusch.

U.S. Government Default?

Greg Ip reports:
Thanks to the advent of credit derivatives -- financial contracts that allow investors to speculate on or protect against default -- we can now observe how likely global markets think it is that Uncle Sam will renege on America's mounting debts. Last week, markets pegged the probability of a U.S. default at 6 percent over the next 10 years, compared with just 1 percent a year ago.

Monday, January 12, 2009

More Spending Stimulus Skeptics

Gary Becker:
Perhaps their [Romer and Bernstein's] estimates of the stimulus provided by direct government spending are in the right ballpark, but I tend to believe that they are excessive. For one thing, the true value of these government programs may be limited because they will be put together hastily, and are likely to contain a lot of political pork and other inefficiencies. For another thing, with unemployment at 7% to 8% of the labor force, it is impossible to target effective spending programs that primarily utilize unemployed workers, or underemployed capital. Spending on infrastructure, and especially on health, energy, and education, will mainly attract employed persons from other activities to the activities stimulated by the government spending. The net job creation from these and related spending is likely to be rather small. In addition, if the private activities crowded out are more valuable than the activities hastily stimulated by this plan, the value of the increase in employment and GDP could be very small, even negative.
Kevin Hassett:
We are in the midst of a crisis caused by so many financial institutions borrowing too much money. Somehow, a critical mass of policy makers now believes that the correct response is for the U.S. government to borrow too much money.

Christy Romer on Fiscal Stimulus

Sunday, January 11, 2009

The Importance of Being Exogenous

I usually don't respond to blogosphere commentary on my work because, after all, time is scarce. But this critique by Nate Silver is noteworthy because the error it makes is so fundamental. It offers a teachable moment.

Silver questions my citation of the Romer tax study in my recent NY Times piece. He writes:
The paper (.pdf) Mankiw refers to, written by Berkley Economists Christina and David Romer, is the sort of thing that will make your head spin. But the gist of it is that (i) It is very important to differentiate the motivation for different types of tax cuts or tax increases, and (ii) a certain type of tax cut or tax increase may have a much larger effect on growth than is generally acknowledged. The type of tax cut that Romer and Romer think falls into this category is what they call an "exogenous" tax cut -- one designed not to counter business cycles, but rather a "spontaneous" tax cut under relatively healthy economic circumstances. This is very much not the type of tax cut that we are contemplating right now.
Essentially, Silver says that the Romers study exogenous tax changes, the tax changes now being contemplated in DC are not exogenous, and therefore the multipliers estimated by the Romers do not apply to thinking about current policy.

This argument raises the question: Why did the Romers focus on exogenous policy changes? The reason is that these are the only changes that can be used to reliability identify the effects of tax policy. If a tax change is made in response to some event, call it X, that influences the economy, it is hard to disentangle the effects of the tax change from the the direct effects of X. The Romers focus on exogenous tax changes for the same reason doctors conduct randomized drugs trials--not because they are interested in randomization as a prescriptive tool, but because randomization solves a statistical identification problem.

Imagine if a clinical doctor reasoned the same way as Silver did. He would say, "All the evidence on the effects of this drug are from randomized drug tests. In my practice, I never randomize treatment of my patients. Therefore, I can safely ignore the results from the randomized experiments."

That is, of course, fallacious. We need the randomized experiments to inform us about the effects of medical interventions, even though interventions in practice are rarely randomized. Similarly, we need to consider the effects of exogenous tax changes, even though many actual tax changes are not at all exogenous.

Principle #4: People respond to incentives

A student at Benedictine College saw this sign and notes, "I could not help but smile and appreciate the presence of the economic theory of incentives in my everyday life."

Saturday, January 10, 2009

On the Spending Stimulus

Click here to read my piece in tomorrow's NY Times.

Obama's Multipliers

Team Obama has released its analysis of fiscal stimulus, coauthored by CEA Chair-designate Christina Romer and Vice President-elect adviser Jared Bernstein. If you go to the penultimate page, you can find the fiscal policy mutlipliers they assume. For government purchases, their multiplier is 1.57; for taxes, 0.99.

These are reasonable figures in light of mainstream models. But, as I pointed out in an earlier post, these models might well have things backward. Apparently, Team Obama is not convinced by the recent research of Christina and David Romer, who conclude:
tax changes have very large effects on output. Our baseline specification suggests that an exogenous tax increase of one percent of GDP lowers real GDP by roughly three percent. Our many robustness checks for the most part point to a slightly smaller decline, but one that is still well over two percent.
That is, Team Obama assumes that tax changes are less than half as potent in influencing the economy as the new CEA Chair estimated them to be in her own research.

Of course, it is prudent to take any research, including that of the very careful, very sensible Romers, with a grain or two of salt. The same can be said of the mainstream models on which Team Obama is relying.

Friday, January 9, 2009

Another Member

...of the Pigou Club:
The chief executive of Exxon Mobil Corp. for the first time called on Congress to enact a tax on greenhouse-gas emissions in order to fight global warming. In a speech in Washington, Rex Tillerson said that a tax was a "more direct, a more transparent and a more effective approach" to curtailing greenhouse gases than other plans popular in Congress and with the incoming Obama administration.
Reported by the Wall Street Journal.

Thursday, January 8, 2009

Fama on Recapitalizing Banks

The great financial economist explains how he would do it. (This piece is at his new blog with Ken French, which will be well worth following for those interested in finance.)

Wednesday, January 7, 2009

Varian on Stimulus

Hal weighs in.

My Favorite Textbook (3e)

A friend sends along this photo of a sock puppet, created by (believe it or not) some White House interns. I am told the puppet is supposed to be of a generic "smart person." He certainly has good taste in reading material.

Tuesday, January 6, 2009

A Strange Pigovian Idea in Oregon

A reader asks about this plan:
Democratic Gov. Theodore R. Kulongoski's upcoming budget calls for a highway tax based on mileage, not gasoline purchases.A state task force will look at equipping every new vehicle in Oregon with a Global Positioning System to record every mile driven and where. Motorists would pay at the gas pump based on how much they drove, no matter how fuel-frugal their vehicle.
This makes sense if you are trying to tax road use and congestion but don't particularly care whether people are driving SmartCars or Hummers. On the other hand, as long as politicians and the public are concerned about fuel efficiency and carbon emissions, as they seem to be, it makes more sense to stick to the more standard gasoline tax.

One possible advantage for the GPS system: You can potentially calibrate the level of the tax to the degree of congestion on the particular road at the particular time of day, so the tax better reflects the changing externality associated with driving. There is no evidence in the article that this varying charge is envisioned, however.

Update: Fred Thompson, a professor at Willamette University in Oregon, offers this input:

I am a faithful reader of your blog and have used your intro text (were I still teaching intro, I'd use it again, although the price is off-putting).

I am writing about Gov. Kulongoski's weight-use mile tax proposal,which deserves, I think, a closer look. The tax is not primarily aimed at gasoline consumption, but is a charge for highway use. The base rate proposed is a quadratic function of axle-weight, times the number of axles and miles travelled, which together with vehicle speed, determines highway wean and tear. However, lighter axle-weight is correlated with fuel consumption (as is speed) and highly fuel efficient vehicles are already eligible for state subsidy.

Of course, one critical advantage of the proposal is that: "You can potentially calibrate the level of the tax to the degree of congestion on the particular road at the particular time of day, so the tax better reflects the changing externality associated with driving." This is, indeed, contemplated in the Gov's proposal,although it is not included in the 2009-11 budget. In the longer run, congestion-pricing will also be useful in maintaining the existing transportation network and necessary for planning its expansion. Moreover, there is not much sense in building the GPS system if you aren't contemplating congestion pricing.

The proposal also contemplates the incorporation of vehicle speed into the base rate in the future. However, like congestion pricing, OR's Department of Transportation hasn't done enough experimentation with this option to understand how it to make it work.

Thanks, Fred.

Monday, January 5, 2009

The Disappearing Money Multiplier

Econ prof Bill Seyfried of Rollins College emails me:
Here's an interesting fact that you may not have seen yet. The M1 money multiplier just slipped below 1. So each $1 increase in reserves (monetary base) results in the money supply increasing by $0.95 (OK, so banks have substantially increased their holding of excess reserves while the M1 money supply hasn't changed by much).
Thanks.

Glaeser on Stimulus

Ed weighs in.

Sunday, January 4, 2009

The Protectionist Threat

Reuters reports:

Both President-elect Barack Obama and Vice President-elect Joe Biden will huddle with Democratic and Republican congressional leaders on Monday to try to advance a huge economic stimulus bill that Obama hopes can be enacted quickly, despite Republican reservations.

Obama's transition team said it is mulling "buy American" provisions for the stimulus package that could favor U.S. companies over foreign competitors.

Let's hope Larry Summers and Christy Romer are successful at beating back this bad idea.

The Progressivity of the Tax System

The CBO has released a new report on effective tax rates (total taxes divided by total income). Compared with previous reports, it includes more information about thin slices at the top of the income distribution. Here are the total effective federal tax rates for 2005, the most recent year available:

Lowest quintile: 4.3 percent
Second quintile: 9.9 percent
Middle quintile: 14.2 percent
Fourth quintile: 17.4 percent
Percentiles 81-90: 20.3 percent
Percentiles 91-95: 22.4 percent
Percentiles 96-99: 25.7 percent
Percentiles 99.0-99.5: 29.7 percent
Percentiles 99.5-99.9: 31.2 percent
Percentiles 99.9-99.99: 32.1 percent
Top 0.01 Percentile: 31.5 percent


N.B.: These figures include all federal taxes, not just income taxes.

Friday, January 2, 2009

Get Ready for a Tough Year

The Young Stars of Economics

As seen by The Economist.

N.B.: Six of the eight have been either Harvard students or Harvard faculty at some point during their careers. And the other two were once targets of Harvard recruitment efforts, which sadly proved unsuccessful.

Here is the previous installment by The Economist.